What makes financial crisis global phenomenon




















The countries in the Triad can be found within the group of rich and developed global economies. The process of opening towards international capital devised by the formulators of economic policies in the emerging countries resulted in the attraction of bulky international investments in the s.

Graph 2 shows the evolution of FDI stocks within the global economy from the s. These stocks grew from 9. Graph 2 shows that the growth of FDI at the global level also to a large extent derives from the increasing productive internationalization of the emerging economies.

Even if the FDI stocks within developed economies continue to be higher than those of emerging countries, this level was substantially reduced from the s. In , for example, Throughout the decade of the s, this percentage was reduced due to the surge of incoming FDI within emerging economies. In and , the flows of FDI that were allocated within emerging economies even surpassed that received by developed economies.

This period is also marked by a deepening of financial globalization. The removal of capital controls and the opening of capital accounts mainly within emerging economies resulted in a significant growth of short-term foreign investments within the global economy Abdelal, This phenomenon becomes evident from the data in Graph 1.

Between and , there was a near ten-doubling in relation to the growth in the international assets and debts within the global economy. This increase is a result not only of the growth in the FDI stocks, but also of the expansion of international banking activities, stock market investments, public and private bonds, and financial market derivatives operations.

Thus, the economic globalization of recent decades is to a large extent a reflection of the gigantic growth of transactions which do not only involve long-term investments, but mainly short-term financial assets that are traded within global financial markets. Global Imbalances and the Collapse of Globalised Finance. Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies. Between the early s and the Asian crisis of , transfers of savings - measured by the world current-account imbalance - barely increased, fluctuating around 1.

These data, referring to the deepening of commercial, productive and financial globalization, merely confirm the perception of a growing internationalization of the global economy in the s and s. Yet, from the advent of the global crisis of , the global economy entered a new phase marked not only by deceleration of global growth, but also by a significant reduction in the indicators for internationalization of the global economy.

In this period, the FDI flows were considerably reduced from The global trade also registered a noticeable reduction, mainly from the last semester of and throughout Even though these rates resumed an upwards trajectory in recent years due to the incipient economic recovery, the speed and the rhythm of this process is inferior to that which was registered throughout the s and until the beginning of the economic crisis of Basel: Bank for International Settlements.

This contraction was even more accentuated within the Euro zone, because of the halting and reversal of the flows of international capital that were redirected towards surplus-generating emerging economies throughout the s Manzi, MANZI, Rafael H. Carta Internacional, Vol. In this regard, the stagnation of globalization of international finances was an event which was more decisive for advanced economies within the Euro Zone, rather than constituting an essentially global phenomenon.

This scenario seems to indicate that the period of accelerated growth of economic globalization reached its endpoint as the global crisis of erupted. Forces of Change in the Post-Crisis World. New York: W. In the s, for the first time since the s, global trade have growing more slowly than the global economy. Big international banks have pulled back to within their home borders, afraid to loan overseas.

The advent of the crisis of had immediate effects on the process of economic globalization. These data only reaffirm the perception that the second phase of globalization which had its beginning from the early s reached its end with the crisis of This conjuncture should not be interpreted as the beginning of a reversal of the process of economic globalization, but should rather be understood as a sign that the phase of more accelerated growth reached its limit with the onset of the global crisis of The economic globalization has entered a new phase which is marked by stagnation of the international economic flows upon the eruption of the global crisis of The motives that explain this process of relative stagnation of the rates of growth in the aggregates linked to global trade, long-term investment, and short-term financial capital is a merger of a series of conjunctural dynamics, which nonetheless also to a large extent reflect global macro trends which had their beginning in the post-crisis global context from Hence, it becomes possible to distinguish dynamics at the political, economic and even ideational levels.

First, the onset of the global crisis of became a landmark within the world economy, which directly reflected upon the process of economic globalization. The extent of the economic recession can only be compared with that which occurred in the Crash of , when the global economy entered the most profound recession of the 20 th century. Its effects also had direct repercussions on the international economic flows. These economies - with exception of China - thereby entered a profound economic recession throughout The global economy only did not undergo a more serious economic recession because of the economic performance of the emerging countries, which despite the crisis still registered a GDP growth of 2.

Yet, the continued downturn in international trade and investment in the s suggests that the stagnation of economic globalization is not only a consequence of the global economic conjuncture. According to a IMF report , p. Weak global growth, particularly weak investment growth, can account for a significant part of the sluggish trade growth, both in absolute terms and relative to GDP.

Empirical analysis suggests that, for the world as a whole, up to threefourths of the decline in trade growth since relative to can be predicted by weaker economic activity, most notably subdued investment growth. While the empirical estimate may overstate the role of output, given the feedback effects of trade policy and trade on growth, a general equilibrium framework suggests that changes in the composition of demand account for about 60 percent of the slowdown in the growth rate of nominal imports relative to GDP.

In other words, the strong reduction in the rate of expansion of international trade is, to some degree, linked to the conjuncture of the world economy in the global post-crisis of But the dynamic of the global economy is by itself insufficient to explain the more persistent process of stagnation in the expansion of international trade from the beginning of the s. Apart from the economic variable, the stagnation of the process of economic globalization is also linked to predominantly political dynamics.

While some of these dynamics are located at the level of national states, others can be situated at the systemic level. With regards to the systemic aspects, the loss of momentum of the economic globalization is a result of the impasses within the global governance agendas.

Washington: Public Affairs. The growth of economic interdependence generated a demand for international regimes in order to resolve the problems related to collective action and convergence of rules and patterns for state conduct, with regards to questions that involved the need for international cooperation.

The slowdown of the global governance agendas was already a visible phenomenon before the eruption of the global crisis of The impasse in the negotiations to finish the Doha Round constitutes an example of the difficulties in the construction of international consensus around the deepening of international cooperation in relation to economic issues Narlikar, NARLIKAR, Amrita.

International Affairs, 3, pp. In any case, these obstacles only became more evident with the crisis of , when the main developed and developing states, faced with the risks of deterioration of the global economic system, decided to pursue mechanisms for the deepening of international cooperation.

The transformation of the financial G20 in a meeting between the leaders of the largest global economies from reflects the need for cooperation and coordination, not least concerning how to manage the international financial crises.

At an initial moment, the G20 successfully reached its main objective which was to diminish the imminent risks of a collapse of the entire global financial system upon the bankruptcy of the North American investment bank, Lehman Brothers. Yet, the reformist drive of the G20 to advance agendas for international cooperation and economic liberalization within the global economy lost momentum throughout the subsequent years upon the financial crisis.

In the words of Mahbubani , p. In this context, the incapacity to deepen the international cooperation might be understood through systemic variables that have made the negotiations more complex. Firstly, there is a growth in the number of actors involved within international negotiations, which naturally results in a greater degree of difficulty in the construction of consensus within the multilateral negotiations.

The first negotiation round of the GATT which took place in counted with the participation of 23 countries. In contrast, the negotiations within the Doha Round initially involved a total of nations. Cambridge: Polity Press. Apart from this, the heterogeneity among the members within the international system has also increased due to the ascent of the emerging countries.

Robbins L The great depression. London, Macmillan. A crash course in the future of finance. The Penguin Press, New York. Schulmeister S Trading practices and price dynamics in commodity markets and the stabilising effects of a transaction tax. Wifo Study, Vienna. Stiglitz JE Free fall. America, free markets, and the sinking of the world economy. Benjamin, New York. Tichy G Why did policy ignore the harbingers of the crisis? Tornell A, Westermann F Boom-bust cycles: facts and explanations, international monetary fund staff papers, 49, , pp — Zeeman EC On the unstable behaviour of stock exchanges.

J Math Econ 1 1 — Download references. You can also search for this author in PubMed Google Scholar. Correspondence to Fritz Breuss. Reprints and Permissions. Breuss, F. Global financial crisis as a phenomenon of stock market overshooting.

Empirica 38, — Download citation. Published : 11 November Issue Date : February Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:. Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article. Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative. Skip to main content. Search SpringerLink Search.

Notes 1. Institutions with dynamic hedges must sell their risky assets, which accelerates the rate of price decrease, which in turn forces more hedged-asset sales.

If many investors have made similar dynamic hedges and are selling, liquidity dries up and prices can free-fall. Insurers such as AIG piled up immense commitments to pay in the event of defaults or capital losses with little capital to back these commitments. When losses hit security markets AIG could not pay off its contracts; it became insolvent.

Ultimately, CDSs made the system more fragile because they facilitated excessive risk-taking. Third, the narrative insists that derivatives unbundle risk, dividing it into simpler segments.

But in fact, sophisticated derivatives such as CDOs re-bundle risk in the most complicated and non-transparent ways: this is what financial engineering and structured derivative products do. Fourth, the celebratory NFA narrative applauded globalisation of financial markets because it created channels of risk dispersion. But securitisation and funding via tightly integrated global capital markets simultaneously created channels of contagion in which a crisis that originated in one product in one location US subprime mortgages quickly spread to other products US prime mortgages, MBSs, CDOs, home equity loans, loans to residential construction companies, credit cards, auto loans, monoline insurance and auction rate securities and throughout the world.

Weber, As noted, structural flaws in the NFA created dangerous leverage throughout the financial system. Annual borrowing by US financial institutions as a percent of gross domestic product GDP jumped from 6. However, in , under pressure from Goldman Sachs chairman and later Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson, it raised the acceptable leverage ratio to 40 times capital and made compliance voluntary Wall Street Watch , , p. This allowed large investment banks to generate asset-to-equity ratios in the mid to upper 30s just before the crisis, with at least half of their borrowing in the form of overnight repos, money that could flee at the first hint of trouble.

Commercial banks appeared to be adequately capitalised, but only because they over-estimated the value of on-balance-sheet assets while holding a high percentage of their most vulnerable assets hidden off-balance-sheet. In fact, they were excessively leveraged, as the crisis revealed. Many European banks had leverage ratios of 50 or more before the crisis Goodhart, , while Citibank's and Bank of America's ratios were even higher Ferguson, By the end of many large banks had seen their equity position evaporate to the brink of insolvency and beyond.

Rising leverage was facilitated in part by the easy money policies of the Fed. To avoid a deep financial crisis following the collapse of the late s stock market and internet booms, the Fed began to cut short-term interest rates in late and continued to hold them at record lows through to mid Financial firms were thus able to borrow cheaply, which, under different circumstances, might have fueled a boom in productive capital investment.

However, given perverse incentives in financial markets, the spectacular returns to financial risk-taking, and a sluggish real economy in which growth was sustained primarily through the impact of rising debt and financial wealth on aggregate demand, the additional funds were mostly used for speculative financial investment. Increased leverage helped push the size of financial markets to unsustainable heights relative to the real economy. The term is usually applied to a cycle phase, but in this case the condition had become secular.

Any serious deterioration in the cash flows required to sustain security prices could have triggered a dangerous de-leveraging process. Falling housing prices and rising mortgage defaults provided that trigger.

Structured financial security price declines were stunning. The downward spiral was exacerbated by the role ratings agencies played in the regulatory system.

Facing a wave of criticism for having led investors astray in the boom with overly optimistic ratings, agencies belatedly shifted assets to higher-risk categories in the crisis.

A small rating downgrade can lead to a large increase in required capital; the relation is not linear.

Banks therefore had to come up with more capital to support their assets. Banks were thus forced to sell assets into a collapsing market. Meanwhile, margin calls forced borrowers to sell securities. The de-leveraging process froze credit markets. Since modern nonfinancial business and household sectors run on credit, the shrinking availability and rising cost of borrowing led to a slowdown in economic growth that in turn worsened the global financial crisis.

The NFA had finally brought the global economy to the edge of the abyss. The past quarter century of deregulation and the globalisation of financial markets, combined with the rapid pace of financial innovation and the moral hazard caused by frequent government bailouts helped create conditions that led to this devastating financial crisis. The severity of the global financial crisis and the global economic recession that accompanied it demonstrate the utter bankruptcy of the deregulated global neoliberal financial system and the market fundamentalism it reflects.

Many of its most influential supporters, including Alan Greenspan, have recanted. Several decades of deregulation and innovation grossly inflated the size of financial markets relative to the real economy. The scope and severity of the current crisis is a clear signal that the growth trajectory of financial markets in recent decades is unsustainable and must be reversed.

It is not possible for the value of financial assets to remain so large relative to the real economy because the real economy cannot consistently generate the cash flows required to sustain such inflated financial claims. It is not economically efficient to have such large proportions of income and human and material resources captured by the financial sector.

Governments thus face a daunting challenge: they have to stop the financial collapse in the short run to prevent a global depression, while orchestrating a major overhaul and contraction of financial markets over the longer run.

The US economy is especially vulnerable because growth over the past few decades has been driven largely by rising household spending on consumption and residential investment. Since real wages were stagnant and real family income growth was slow, rising household spending was increasingly driven by the combined effects of rising debt and the increase in household wealth created by stock market and housing booms.

This dynamic process has reversed direction in the crisis. The saving rate is rising rapidly as households repay debt and attempt to rebuild wealth to create a cushion against job and income loss. Meanwhile, wealth is evaporating. Falling wealth along with deteriorating labour market conditions and declining business investment spending have caused aggregate demand to collapse.

Governments have been wise to use public funds as a partial counterweight to the impact of falling private spending on aggregate demand. Indeed, more needs to be done in this regard. It was also sensible to use public money to slow the rate of financial collapse, though the US government in particular has been spectacularly inefficient in its financial intervention policies.

Nevertheless, in the longer run the financial system must shrink by a substantial amount. The Economist insists that: The financial-services industry is condemned to suffer a horrible contraction…. It is hard to believe that financial services create enough value to command such pre-eminence in the economy.

The Economist , For such a transition to be effective, two difficult tasks must be accomplished. Efficient financial theory must be replaced as the guide to policy making by the more realistic theories associated with Keynes and Minsky, and domination of financial policy making by the Lords of Finance must end. The design and implementation of the changes needed in financial markets is a political as much as an economic challenge. Unfortunately, most elected officials responsible for overseeing US financial markets have been strongly influenced by efficient market ideology and corrupted by campaign contributions and other emoluments lavished on them by financial corporations.

Moreover, powerful appointed officials in the Treasury Department, the SEC, the Federal Reserve System and other agencies responsible for financial market oversight are often former employees of large financial institutions who return to their firms or lobby for them after their time in office ends. Their material interests are best served by letting financial corporations do as they please in a lightly regulated environment. We have, in the main, appointed foxes to guard our financial chickens.

Unfortunately, the people President Obama has selected to guide his administration's financial rescue and reregulation programmes are almost uniquely unqualified to accomplish the dual objectives of down-sizing financial markets and eliminating dangerous securities. As president of the New York Federal Reserve Bank, Geithner had responsibility for seeing that giant financial conglomerates such as Citigroup avoided excessive risk, a task at which he failed miserably.

He neither restrained their risk-taking nor warned the public that they had become excessively risky. Geithner also bears substantial responsibility for the inefficiency of the financial rescue operations undertaken to date.

For example, much of the Troubled Asset Relief Program in effect used taxpayer money to finance bonuses for top bank employees and dividends for shareholders with no positive impact on financial market performance. His main impact on bank policy was to push for the kind of aggressive risk taking that crashed the firm. The President has, in other words, put the task of shrinking and tightly regulating financial markets in the hands of advisors who do not believe in strong regulation and have spent their entire careers opposing it.

This may explain why he has yet to take, or even express support for, the kinds of effective government intervention required to end the financial crisis without recreating the conditions that caused it.

His strategy seems to be to spend whatever public funds are necessary to restore profitability to financial markets as currently constituted, and only then to consider new regulation. But if financial markets become healthy again, the political pressure to reregulate will have vanished. This was bad analysis, bad policy, and terrible politics. This administration, elected on the promise of change, has already managed, in an astonishingly short time, to create the impression that it's owned by the wheeler-dealers.

Krugman, Until this administration adopts a radical change of course in its financial market policies, US and global financial markets are likely to remain fatally structurally flawed.

Issues treated here are also addressed in other publications Crotty, ; Crotty and Epstein, Google Scholar. Google Preview. See Crotty for an explanation of the historical economic and political processes through which the neoliberal regime came to replace Golden Age institutions and practices. An analysis of the effects of perverse incentives in different market segments is presented in Crotty, Ratings agencies also gave large investment banks like Lehman and Merrill Lynch solid investment grade ratings that allowed them to borrow cheaply.

SIVs contributed to the non-transparency of financial markets. See Bookstabber and Das for concrete examples of the risk- and complexity-augmenting properties of structured financial products. Half of the spectacular rise in investment bank's return on equity in the four years leading up to the crisis was generated by higher leverage rather than smart investing, efficient innovation or even boom-induced capital gains on trading assets. It is possible, but not likely, that Europe will act independently of the USA and aggressively reregulate their financial markets.

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide. Sign In or Create an Account. Sign In. Advanced Search. Search Menu. Article Navigation. Close mobile search navigation Article Navigation.



0コメント

  • 1000 / 1000